The Bradbury Pound Could Be a Forgotten Solution to Economic Woes
In the annals of British financial history, there lies a curious footnote that some believe could hold the key to solving modern economic crises. This forgotten piece of fiscal ingenuity is known as the Bradbury Pound, an emergency currency introduced in the United Kingdom at the outbreak of World War I in 1914. As the nation teeters on the brink of yet another economic downturn, with talks of a £22 billion black hole in the budget, some are calling for a fresh look at this century-old monetary experiment.
The story of the Bradbury Pound begins on 4th August 1914, when Britain declared war on Germany. As news of the conflict spread, panic gripped the nation’s financial institutions. Citizens, fearing the worst, queued outside banks to withdraw their savings, threatening to deplete the gold reserves that underpinned the monetary system of the time. The Bank of England, a private institution despite its name, found itself in a precarious position, having issued more paper notes than it could back with actual gold.
In response to this looming crisis, the Treasury took an extraordinary step. Under the Bank Notes and Currency Act, hastily passed through Parliament in just two days, the Treasury was empowered to issue its own currency. These notes, which came to be known as Bradbury Pounds after Sir John Bradbury, the first Secretary to the Treasury who signed them, were not backed by gold but by the “wealth and labour potential of the country”.
This move effectively circumvented the Bank of England and the private banking system. The Bradbury Pounds were debt-free and interest-free, created by the government for the people. They were accepted everywhere, from high street banks to market stalls, and played a crucial role in stabilising the economy during the tumultuous early days of the war.
However, the reign of the Bradbury Pound was short-lived. By 1917, the Treasury had reverted to borrowing money from the Bank of England at interest, a move that some argue laid the groundwork for the massive national debt we grapple with today.
Now, over a century later, as the UK faces economic challenges that echo those of 1914, there are calls to revisit the principles behind the Bradbury Pound. Proponents argue that the government could, and should, create its own money based on the nation’s wealth, rather than borrowing from private banks at interest.
The concept is not without its critics. Mainstream economists warn of the potential for runaway inflation if money creation is not carefully controlled. However, supporters counter that the current system, where private banks create money through lending, is itself inflationary and prone to boom-and-bust cycles.
At the heart of this debate lies a fundamental question about the nature of money itself. Is it merely a convenient unit of exchange, or does it represent something more tangible? The Bradbury Pound was based on the idea that a nation’s currency should reflect its real wealth – its infrastructure, resources, and the productive capacity of its people.
This idea challenges the current global financial system, where central banks, including the Bank of England, coordinate their policies through institutions like the Bank for International Settlements in Basel, Switzerland. Critics argue that this system places the control of money creation in the hands of unelected, unaccountable entities that operate largely in secret.
To bring these issues to the fore, an open letter has been penned to the Chancellor of the Exchequer, Rachel Reeves. The letter poses four key questions about money creation and the relationship between the Treasury, the Bank of England, and international financial institutions.
The first question asks whether the Chancellor receives full briefings from the Governor of the Bank of England after his bimonthly meetings at the Bank for International Settlements. These meetings, where central bank governors from around the world gather to discuss global monetary policy, are conducted without formal minutes, raising questions about transparency and accountability.
The second question addresses the legal status of the City of London, the square mile at the heart of Britain’s financial district. Some economists argue that the City operates as a “state within a state”, with its own unique legal privileges. The letter asks how, if this is the case, the Bank of England can be allowed to control the nation’s finances from what is effectively foreign soil.
The third question delves into history, asking whether the Chancellor is aware of the events of 7th August 1914, when the Bradbury Pound was introduced. This question aims to gauge the government’s knowledge and understanding of alternative monetary policies that have been successfully implemented in the past.
The final and perhaps most crucial question asks whether, given the evidence presented, the Chancellor will consider expanding the money supply directly through the Treasury, effectively creating a modern version of the Bradbury Pound. This would involve bypassing the private banking system and creating debt-free, interest-free money based on the nation’s wealth.
Advocates for monetary reform are urging citizens to send this letter to their Members of Parliament, particularly targeting the 300-plus new MPs who may not yet be fully entrenched in the current system. The hope is to spark a debate in Parliament about monetary policy and the potential for sovereign money creation.
However, critics of this approach argue that giving politicians direct control over money creation could lead to abuse and economic instability. They point to historical examples of hyperinflation in countries where governments have printed money without restraint.
Proponents counter that a properly structured system of sovereign money creation would include checks and balances to prevent such abuses. They suggest the creation of an independent body, separate from both the government and the banking sector, to oversee money creation based on the real needs of the economy.
The debate over monetary reform touches on fundamental questions about democracy, sovereignty, and the nature of wealth. In an era of growing wealth inequality and recurring financial crises, these questions are more pertinent than ever.
As the UK grapples with its economic challenges, the story of the Bradbury Pound serves as a reminder that alternative approaches to money and finance are possible. Whether such ideas will gain traction in the corridors of power remains to be seen, but the conversation itself is a valuable one, encouraging citizens to think critically about the financial systems that underpin our society.
In the end, the debate over the Bradbury Pound and sovereign money creation is not just about economics. It’s about the kind of society we want to create and the values we wish to prioritise. As we face the economic challenges of the 21st century, perhaps it’s time to look back to the innovations of the past for inspiration. The Bradbury Pound may be a footnote in history, but its principles continue to challenge our understanding of money, wealth, and the role of government in managing the economy.